GROWTH! What Growth?

Intro image

Alf_Hornborg writes in his article “How to turn an ocean liner”:  “Although soon reduced to a heterodox and marginalized position, the critique of growth has continued to challenge mainstream dogmas of economics and policy for over four decades. Countless debates have raged on what exactly is the problem of sustainability, whether the design of taxes and subsidies, the choice of energy sources, the internal contradictions of capitalism, or even the biological essence of the human species. Considering the centrality of the focus on the economy, it is remarkable how little attention has been paid to the phenomenon of money. Mainstream economists certainly do not question money, but neither do most Marxists or ecological economists. Even Georgescu-Roegen (1971), who is recognized as the origin of both ecological economics and the proposal for degrowth, wrote a 457-page book on the contradiction between economics and thermodynamics without once asking if the cultural convention we know as money might in fact be the elephant in the room.”         Alf Hornborg  How_to_turn_an_ocean_liner   GM PDF here


what (de)growth? – related GaiaMoney posts and pages


What type of growth of what ?

a – bio growth  b – linear  c – exponential


population growth

Annual world population since 10 thousand bce for owid


Peak human =10 bn?  see GaiaMoney page on population and demography


product/industry/sector growth


Global CO2 emissions from cement production

Global CO2 emissions from cement production


articles + books


The Delusion and Danger of Infinite Economic Growth. How economists came to ignore the natural world. By CHRISTOPHER F. JONES

Economists have only begun to model never-ending growth over the last 75 years. Before that, they had ignored the topic for a century.  And before that, they had believed in limits.

The founding fathers of economics—luminaries including Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and John Stuart Mill—shared a belief that growth was finite, and that the reason for limits lay in the natural world. Writing in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, they based this conclusion on three observations. First, there was a limited supply of land. Second, all economic processes required at least some products of the land as raw materials. And third, the productivity of the land was subject to the law of diminishing marginal returns: each additional bit of labor and capital added to a plot of land will offer less and less benefit until no more gains are possible. Until the middle of the nineteenth century, leading economists recognized the interdependence of natural and economic systems.

While Adam Smith considered this inevitable slowing of growth to be “dull” and “melancholy,” others were optimistic. John Stuart Mill thought the stationary state would come when there was enough to satisfy human needs, and embraced its arrival, writing in 1848 that it “would be a very considerable improvement on our present condition [with] much room for improving the art of living” when humans could abandon the rat race of endlessly pursuing more. Whether good or bad, the end of growth was a matter of when, not if, for the classical economists.

So when did growth become infinite? If you had to pick a Hans Christen Anderson for the fairytale of eternal economic growth, American economist Robert Solow would be your man. Solow launched modern growth theory with a pair of pioneering articles written in 1956 and 1957. Still alive today, he has done more to shape growth theory than any other thinker.
Like Abramovitz and Lewis, Solow turned his attention to growth in the 1950s because the topic was “in the air.” Calculations of Gross National Product (GNP) had been pioneered during World War II and were spreading across the globe. Fueled by international competition and the reality of robust economic expansion in many nations, growth had quickly become the catchword of the day in economics departments and government bureaucracies.

Solow advanced these discussions with a new model of growth, one that sought to analyze the relative contributions of capital, labor, and technical progress. Whereas Smith, Ricardo, and Mill had taken for granted that land was one of the three factors of production with labor and capital, Solow assumed that land did not matter. To the extent that land or natural resources merited mention (and they rarely did), they could be seen as a sub-category of capital, interchangeable with money or machines.
Ignoring land meant cutting the natural world out of modern growth theory at its inception. Solow wrote that this seemed the “natural assumption” to make in a theory of growth, though he did not specify why. And since in the 1950s, abundant land and resources appeared available, few would have disagreed. Moreover, Solow was a modeler, and the chief virtue of a good model is that it simplifies. A map of a city that included every detail would be as large as the city itself, of course, and of no real use. With bottomless pools of oil in the Middle East, extensive minerals from developing nations, and swaths of farmland available, why clutter a model by including them?

With the rise of the environmental movement in the late 1960s, however, this assumption was called into question. And nowhere was the attack stronger than in the blockbuster 1972 report The Limits to Growth, in which an MIT team commissioned by the Club of Rome argued ecosystem collapse would be the inevitable result of exponential growth. Solow called the report “worthless as science” and “ignorance masquerading as knowledge.” Integrating natural resources into his growth model in 1974, he argued with complex mathematics that “the world can, in effect, get along without natural resources.”

“How dare you,” Thunberg might easily have scolded.

But while readers might imagine Solow to be a laissez-faire fundamentalist beholden to corporate interests, in reality, he was a left-of-center thinker committed to government intervention and planetary protection. He wrote about abating pollution and joined a Sierra Club board. And he scoffed at infinite models: The real world is so complex that to predict more than twenty years into the future is foolhardy, he once told a Congressional committee.

Solow was partly right to critique sloppy thinking among some environmentalists. Limits to Growth did not take account of the ways increased prices or technological advances make new resources available. Nor did such reports account for the fact that from the 1940s to the 1970s, most natural resources did not become demonstrably more scarce. Plus, Solow noted, a no-growth economy could still be highly wasteful. Pollution, not growth, should be the focus of environmentalists.
The specific blind spot in his model was climate change. When thinking about economic growth, he and other economists focused exclusively on inputs to the production process. Would we have enough coal, oil, iron, and minerals to make new goods? With price signals, substitution, and technological change, Solow and his colleagues were convinced we would. But they did not consider outputs—waste and pollution—to be more than a nuisance. They did not imagine that greenhouse gas emissions could be so consequential as to threaten ecosystem integrity in ways that could affect growth.
Similarly, Solow didn’t consider how his ideas would be used by others. His footnotes and caveats showed he didn’t think it made sense to talk about infinite growth. But few people read footnotes and caveats, particularly busy politicians. The easy and convenient takeaway from his models has been that growth can proceed regardless of planetary conditions, and Solow did little throughout his career to correct this misinterpretation.

Perhaps the relative newness of the idea of eternal economic growth can give us hope. In demanding an accounting of growth better suited to today’s problems—one that takes planetary boundaries seriously—we do not need to overturn fixed or timeless laws of nature. As we grapple with the growing dangers of climate change, we can create fresh models and write different stories. That may mean returning to the field’s origins: a time when ideas of growth and the natural world were intertwined.

read newrepublic article here            christopherfjones.com

 


Despite the global dominance of capitalism, economic growth continues to trend downward. Mainstream economists blame the slowdown on various ‘distortions’, but as this animation shows, the reality is quite different. Capitalists seek not more income per se, but greater power-through-redistribution, which they achieve by strategically stymying growth.       more on youtube

 


positivemoney.org     The Tragedy of Growth   To protect wellbeing and avoid ecological disaster we must abandon GDP growth and transform our economic system    by David Barmes + Fran Boait      Critiques of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) as a measure of economic progress are widespread. However ‘beyond GDP’ narratives often seek to complement the dominant indicator with other measures of progress, aiming for ‘inclusive’ or ‘green’ growth, instead of truly moving ‘beyond GDP’.


Language and Economics pdf here   2014  Crisis in the habitat of the economic growth monster  by  Emil Urhammer

Economic growth is also present in semiotic discourse4. A researcher from a think tank reported, based on his observation of governmental departments that he had seen banners on the walls promoting economic growth and, according to him, economic growth is engrained in these departments to such an extent that it extends beyond theoretical equations to a general discourse promoting economic growth as an ultimate good and the solution to all our problems. Additionally, Seaford observes “[…] that in practice GDP does tend to be treated rather like a single welfare function” (Seaford 2013:27), an observation also supported by Fioramonti, who confirms the widespread use of economic growth as a proxy for wellbeing (Fioramonti 2013). Thus, the  economic growth discourse has shaped the ability to imagine what wellbeing is by reducing it to a monetary phenomenon. To use Fioramonti’s formulation, this shaping is a form of domination, or discursive power (Haugaard 2003), which can also be detected in the ability to determine what wealth and valuable contributions to society entail, namely increased GDP, as well as that which contributes to this increase, regardless of social and environmental consequences (Fioramonti 2013).


economicsfromthetopdown blog   2020  , Carey W King   The Economic Superorganism: Beyond the Competing Narratives on Energy, Growth, and Policy    –  review by Blair Fix   –

“If you are interested in the megatrends of the 21st century, then Carey King’s new book The Economic Superorganism should be on your reading list. It is a well-written, meticulously researched opus on how to understand the sustainability problems that face humanity.

Several other recent books have delved into the role of energy in driving economic growth. (For instance, Energy and the Wealth of Nations and The Economic Growth Engine). Yet King’s book is unique, because he has framed his arguments in a surprising way.1 He has focused on narratives.

Before discussing King’s narrative framework, it’s worth pausing for some reflection. Scientists who study the biophysical limits of the human economy run head-on into a cultural divide between the natural and social sciences. These ‘two cultures’ (as C.P. Snow called them) do not speak the same language.”

 


ecological economics – Macroeconomic narratives in a world of crises  2013   Emil Urhammer & Inge Røpke   An analysis of stories about solving the system crisis  –  abstract  The study thus contributes to the long line of analyses on discourses on sustainable economy: empirically, by investigating and analysing a number of macroeconomic proposals for solving the system crisis, and theoretically, by elaborating on the concept of narrative dynamics in relation to persuasive strength in political decision-making.  –  “…two opposing conceptions have led to the emergence of two different discourses as regards the dilemma of growth; here, we characterise these as a pro-growth and a no-growth discourse, respectively.”


 

academia.eu  read or download pdf here   2013  Post-growth policy instruments   Peter Ferguson

This paper proposes a framework to evaluate post-growth policy instruments which gauges their capacity to lessen the pressure for growth emanating from the labour market and the state’s contradictory legitimisation and accumulation imperatives, whilst increasing societal well-being and reducing the biophysical throughput of the economy. It is argued that the most effective policies to do this are measures to reduce average working hours, expand low productivity sectors and reduce inequality. Specific policies instruments include public sector expansion and the promotion of cooperatives, the introduction of citizens’ basic income schemes, environmental tax reform, the abolition of fossil fuel subsidies, reforms to monetary policy, financial regulatory reform and the introduction of alternative measures of progress to gross domestic product.


academia.edu  2009  Advancing_and_Resolving_the Great Sustainability Debates and Discourses – Resolving the “Growth versus Sustainability Debates”  through  “Green Growth/Decoupling”  to Progress the “Climate Change Debates”    M Smith


paulromer.net/   The Deep Structure of Economic Growth   by Paul Romer 

When I was working on growth in the 1990s, I wrote an article on economic growth … deep conceptual foundations. We can share discoveries with others. There are incomprehensibly many discoveries yet to be found. The economic jargon for this first point is the “nonrivalry of knowledge;” the jargon from math and computer science for the second point is “combinatorial explosion.”  …   The challenge for growth theory is to understand why growth in China was so much faster after reform than before …  To understand how persistent growth, even accelerating growth is possible, it helps to step back and ask where growth comes from. At the most basic level, an economy grows when whenever people take resources and rearrange them in a way that makes them more valuable. …

Every generation has perceived the limits to growth that finite resources and undesirable side effects would pose if no new recipes or ideas were discovered. And every generation has underestimated the potential for finding new recipes and ideas. We consistently fail to grasp how many ideas remain to be discovered. The difficulty is the same one we have with compounding: possibilities do not merely add up; they multiply. …    there have been two few people on earth and too little time since we showed up, for us to have tried more than a minuscule fraction of the all the possibilities. …   If we think of an idea as a recipe that shows how to create value by rearranging physical objects, it makes sense to define a meta-idea as a recipe for social interaction that encourages the production and transmission of ideas. Growth comes from ideas about objects. Meta-ideas are ideas about ideas. …  One of the biggest meta-ideas of modern life is to let people live together in dense urban agglomerations. A second is to allow market forces to guide most of the detailed decisions these people make about who they interact with each other. … The third big meta-idea is the system of science …           read whole article here

 


thebreakthrough.org/  Seven Billion Solutions Strong    Why Markets, Growth and Innovation Are the Antidote to Eco-Pessimism        


coppolacomment.com   16/3/2021    From Carbon To Metals: the Renewable Energy Transition   By Frances Coppola

The world is transitioning from a carbon-intensive to a metals-intensive economy. Low-carbon technologies use much larger amounts of metal than traditional fossil fuel-based systems. Demand for metals is thus rising exponentially, fuelling a boom in mining and production.

But this creates an environmental challenge. Metals extraction and processing is a significant contributor to global warming and a major pollutant. Unless more environmentally-friendly ways of generating energy from renewable sources can be found, saving the planet from carbon emissions may prove extremely costly for our fellow creatures and even for ourselves.


capitalaspower.com/2015/10/putting-power-back-into-growth-theory/

Putting Power Back into Growth Theory


Queen’s PhD_Thesis   2017  Towards a Critical Theory of the Anthropocene and a Life-affirming Politics – A Post-Anthropocentric, Post-Growth, Post-(neo)Liberal Green Republican Analysis Anne FREMAUX  Supervisor: Prof. John BARRY


FT 2019 Capital Rethinking Growth

FT 2019 Fund chiefs rethinking Growth

 


EEB 2019  Decoupling Debunked.   Evidence and arguments against green growth as a sole strategy for sustainability  by Joachim H Spangenberg, Christian Kerschner, Alejo Kraus-Polk


thebreakthrough.org      Decoupling or Degrowth?    2018    Why “Peak Stuff” May Not Be As Dire As You’ve Heard     by 

“Does humanity’s growing use of materials mean that decoupling is impossible? In a word, no, and attempts to reduce all resource and environmental problems to our material footprint won’t help us solve problems of resource scarcity or environmental impacts.  In a recent article … Jason Hickel claims  that humanity can only consume 50 billion tons of “stuff” each year (compared to current consumption levels at about 80 billion tons). And according to several papers that Hickel cites, that can’t be achieved in the foreseeable future, given growing populations and economies. The only solution, according to Hickel, is to ditch our addiction to GDP growth.  Hickel is challenging the concept of “green growth,” which he describes as “absolute decoupling of GDP from material use.” But before talking about evidence for or against decoupling, it’s important to ask: decoupling of what? ” 


globalpolicyjournal.com     Degrowth:  Solving the Impasse by Magical Thinking  23/2/2021   Branko Milanovic outlines the ideological divides and rhetorical tactics distinguishing degrowers and growers.


The Paradox of Choice: Why More Is Less, 2009  by Barry Schwartz The Paradox of Choice: Why More Is Less, Revised Edition by [Barry Schwartz]

 


researchgate.net/   2020   Happier with less? Members of European environmental grassroots initiatives reconcile lower carbon footprints with higher life satisfaction and income increases  –  GLAMURS (Green Lifestyles, Alternative Models and Up-scaling Regional Sustainability) –  Gibran Vita, Diana Ivanova, Adina Dumitru, Ricardo Garcia-Mira

Scientists and policymakers recognize the need to address consumption and lifestyles in order to reconcile environmental and development agendas. Sustainability-oriented grassroots initiatives emerge bottom-up to create opportunities for sustainable lifestyles; yet no prior assessment has ascertained the efficacy of their members to reduce carbon footprints (CF) and enhance well-being. We compare the CF of non-members and members of grassroots initiatives in the domains of food, clothing, housing and transport. We further compare the groups by testing the influence of socio-economic variables that are typically associated with both footprint and well-being. Here we show that grassroots initiative members have 16% lower total carbon footprint, and 43% and 86% lower carbon footprints for food and clothing respectively, compared to their “non-member” regional socio- demographic counterparts. We find a higher adoption of some energy-saving behaviors for initiative members such as greater active travel distance and lower indoor temperatures in the winter, yet no significant differences in the CF of housing and transport. Interestingly, increases in income are not associated with increases in the total CF of members, while the influence of income is confirmed for the CF of the total sample. Instead, factors such as age, household size, and gender better explain the variation in the domain-specific CFs of initiative members. Finally, members show higher life satisfaction compared to non-members and are 11–13% more likely to evaluate their life positively. Our results suggest that initiative members uncover lifestyle features that not only enable lower emissions, but also reconcile emissions with income and well-being. 

download PDF at researchgate.net


minipost.com article 2019

People who significantly lower their carbon footprint report greater life satisfaction, study finds

 


The_Sustainable_Development_Goals_ GM PDF here  2020   The Sustainable Development Goals prioritize economic growth over sustainable resource use: a critical reflection from a socio‑ecological perspective     Nina Eisenmenger · Melanie Pichler · Nora Krenmayr · Dominik Noll · Barbara Plank · Ekaterina Schalmann · Marie‑Theres Wandl · Simone Gingrich

Abstract :  The sustainable development goals (SDGs) were adopted in 2015, succeeding the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs). While the MDGs focused on improving well-being in the developing world, the 17 SDGs address all countries and aim at reconciling economic and social with ecological goals. We adopt a social ecology perspective and critically reflect on the SDGs’ potential for monitoring, supporting, and bringing about a transformation towards sustainability. Starting from a literature review on the SDGs, we link empirical findings from social ecology with analyses of SDG targets and indicators.

First, we find that the SDGs fail to monitor absolute trends in resource use and thus prioritize economic growth over ecological integrity.

Second, we discuss the contradictions between economic growth and sustainable resource use in early and late stages of industrialization processes and show that they are responsible for important trade-offs among SDG targets.

Third, we analyze the transformative potential of the SDGs with a focus on the actors and institutions addressed to bring about transformative change. We find that the SDGs rely mainly on those institutions responsible for unsustainable resource use, and partly propose measures that even reinforce current trends towards less sustainability. Despite ascertaining limited transformative potential to the SDGs from an analytical perspective, we conclude by stressing the strategic relevance of the SDGs for visions, research, and practices of statt towards transformative change towards sustainability.


Jason Nickel  2018  The contradiction of the sustainable development goals:  Growth versus ecology on a finite planet

There are two sides to the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs), which appear at risk of contradiction. One calls for humanity to achieve “harmony with nature”… The other calls for continued global economic growth equivalent to 3% per year … The SDGs assume that efficiency improvements will suffice to reconcile the tension between growth and ecological sustainability. This paper draws on empirical data to test whether this assumption is valid, paying particular attention to two key ecological indicators: resource use and CO2 emissions.  The results show that global growth of 3% per year renders it empirically infeasible to achieve … (rapid enough) … reductions in aggregate.  … The paper presents alternative pathways for realizing human development objectives that rely on reducing inequality … rather than aggregate growth.


https://iopscience.iop.org   2019   Connecting global emissions to fundamental human needs and their satisfaction  by Gibran Vita, Edgar G Hertwich, Konstantin Stadler  and Richard Wood  –  © Environmental Research LettersVolume 14Number 1     DownloadArticle PDF     DownloadArticle ePub

Abstract
While quality of life (QOL) is the result of satisfying human needs, our current provision strategies result in global environmental degradation. To ensure sustainable QOL, we need to understand the environmental impact of human needs satisfaction. In this paper we deconstruct QOL, and apply the fundamental human needs framework developed by Max-Neef et al to calculate the carbon and energy footprints of subsistence, protection, creation, freedom, leisure, identity, understanding and participation. We find that half of global carbon emissions are driven by subsistence and protection. A similar amount are due to freedom, identity, creation and leisure together, whereas understanding and participation jointly account for less than 4% of global emissions. We use 35 objective and subjective indicators to evaluate human needs satisfaction and their associated carbon footprints across nations. We find that the relationship between QOL and environmental impact is more complex than previously identified through aggregated or single indicators. Satisfying needs such as protection, identity and leisure is generally not correlated with their corresponding footprints. In contrast, the likelihood of satisfying needs for understanding, creation, participation and freedom, increases steeply when moving from low to moderate emissions, and then stagnates. Most objective indicators show a threshold trend with respect to footprints, but most subjective indicators show no relationship, except for freedom and creation. Our study signals the importance of considering both subjective and objective satisfaction to assess QOL-impact relationships at the needs level. In this way, resources could be strategically invested where they strongly relate to social outcomes, and spared where non-consumption satisfiers could be more effective. Through this approach, decoupling human needs satisfaction from environmental damage becomes more attainable.

Play Video Download video Download transcript


academia.edu/PhDthesis   2018   The Environmental Impacts of HumanNeeds and Lifestyles:  Connecting the global economy, naturalresources and human well-being   Gibran Vita

Preface :  The field of Industrial Ecology (IE) proposes a systems perspective on sustainability issues. It relies on apowerful set of analytical tools to understand human-nature relationships beyond the disjointedapproaches of disciplinary silos. In practice, the field has focused on accounting tools to describe socio-economic metabolism and technical systems, while the role of human well-being and social systemsremains beyond the boundaries of IE work.Indeed, IE tools have been essential to mapping interlinkages between economic development andenvironmental problems. However, most IE solutions remain in the technological sphere or within thestatus-quo. Without losing its roots, IE has the potential to embed a stronger social perspective bydrawing on the narratives and methods of social sciences. This is a natural step if industrial ecology is toshed light on sustainability pathways that are socially, technically and environmentally sound.Sustainability science is inherently political. The research question, methodological approach and resultinterpretation are susceptible to the values and world views of the researcher. In my view, our role asscientists is to expand human consciousness into perceiving, understanding and assimilating thecomplexity and inter-connectedness of the worlds needs and resources beyond the apparent. In this PhD, I make an effort towards holistic research while staying true to the roots of industrial ecology, without forgetting my own roots. My hope is to be of service to human and non-human life. In this case, my goal is to contribute to illuminating pathways towards more harmonious and flourishing life for all creation.             read or download here       >DEGROWTH,

THE GROWTH ILLUSION   HOW ECONOMIC GROWTH HAS ENRICHED THE FEW, IMPOVERISHED THE MANY, AND ENDANGERED THE PLANET    1992   Richard Douthwaite

The premise of this book is that economic growth has made life considerably worse for people in Britain since 1955 and that, even if growth were beneficial at one stage in human history ,it is now damaging. The book presents evidence of social and environmental damage caused by growth and several reasons for a persistence of growth in the face of this damage. It is proposed that the real reason growth has not been stopped is that economic systems would collapse if it did. The book looks at the effects of a policy of growth before and after the 1950s, how growth has effected national health and damaged family and community life, and the effects of growth on the environment (see especially chapter 11:”Growth in the Greenhouse”). Included is an examination of how the need for growth forces companies to adopt new technologies before their impact on the environment can be assessed, how politicians are more concerned about maintaining conditions in which economic growth is possible than holding the world’s climate unchanged, the myth of sustainable growth, and a lack of morality governing the direction of economic change. A solution is proposed that involves adjusting the capitalist system.(LZ)

The Growth Illusion   Richard Douthwaite  1992       read or dowload PDF here

 


Boris Frankel Fictions of Sustainability

Fictions of Sustainability: The Politics of Growth and Post-Capitalist Futures     By Boris Frankel

This book discusses the growing political contest between conservative and reform-orientated defenders of capitalist societies on the one side, and the policies and imagined futures advanced by green and socialist critics on the other. All are subjected to detailed scrutiny. Is ‘green growth’ innovation able to resolve deep-seated global inequality and other socio-political and environmental problems? Can new technology sustain capitalist production and high consumption by decoupling economic growth from the limits of nature? How feasible or utopian are ‘post-work’ or post-capitalist societies based on full automation and a universal basic income? What are the political economic strengths and weaknesses of green post-growth or degrowth proposals? These and other crucial issues are analysed by the author in a challenging and thought-provoking book covering an extensive range of policy reports, social theories, environmental proposals and political practices across the world.        read or download PDF here

 

 

 

 


Growth Critique in the 1970s Crisis and Today: Malthusianism, Social Mechanics, and Labor Discipline    Maria Markantonatou   Department of Sociology, University of the Aegean, Lesvos, Greece

ABSTRACT : This article examines the perspective on labor in two critiques of “growth” as elaborated in the context of two capitalist crises: the Keynesian model of industrial development in the 1970s, and the neoliberal finance capitalist growth model of today. A landmark event for the first critique was the publication of the “Limits to Growth” report, and for the second the emergence of the “degrowth” theoretical current. Both critiques have a Malthusian point of departure, and their view on overpopulation is accordingly discussed. Comparison between them shows that despite their ecological and supposedly socially and politically neutral point of departure, both bodies of critique examined here—that of the 1970s and the contemporary one—prescribe for labor the obligation of social discipline and acceptance of labor-market insecurity, along with the undermining of welfare rights. First, I argue that there is no such thing as an ahistorical critique of growth, but only critiques of different, casespecific models of growth in each particular instance. Second, I argue that the idea of a steady-state economy that predominates in growth critical programs is incompatible with the process of expansion and continual enlargement inherent to capitalism. Finally, I argue that, in the framework of two different crises, both critiques of growth promoted a vision of social pacification and, on the basis of ecological arguments, justified the preservation of capitalist power relations               download PDF here

 


uneven development


econlib.org     The two China policies  By Scott Sumner   The Economist has an article showing a dramatic difference in economic growth between northern and southern China:   The Economist provides a number of explanations for this gap, but barely even alludes to the most important; southern China is considerably more capitalist than northern China.


https://www.theguardian.com/artanddesign/2021/mar/24/chinas-rural-revolution-architects-rescuing-villages-oblivion-tofu-rice-wine-lotus-tea


more articles


https://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/right-now-it-feels-like-anything-can-derail-everything-so-are-theories-of-change-still-useful/


corporatefinanceinstitute.com   Different  Economics Theories of Growth?  1.Classical Growth Theory    2.Neoclassical Growth Model   3.Endogenous Growth Theory

 


 greenergrowth.co.uk     Greener Growth is a community interest company that takes neglected areas and makes them food-producing and biodiversity-enhancing.

 


Brussels Blog posted by on 3rd Oct 2019

Last Saturday, in the middle of the night, I was listening to Business Matters on the BBC World Service. At 18.30 minutes into the programme, there is a piece on the Greta Thunberg’s speech to the UN. She said:

“We are in the beginning of a mass extinction and all you can talk about is money and fairy tales of eternal economic growth. How dare you.”

Professor Mody thought Greta’s speech was a very important statement, “cutting out a political path on which economists must now travel”.

However…   read more 


 

GretaThunbergMarch.jpg

Greta Thunberg Is Right. Fairy Tales of Endless Growth Will Destroy Us
Growth is driving climate change. But news media ignore the clear connection.

Jennifer Ellen Good 30 Sep 2019  TheTyee.ca

… “There are many reasons why people are still talking about Thunberg’s speech … at the United Nations Climate Action Summit. She spoke with knowledge, clarity and passion well beyond her years.

What I find especially significant about the talk is her inclusion of a critique of economic growth in the climate change story frame. … Scholars and activists share Thunberg’s concerns about the current system of endless economic growth. For example …  read more

 


Floods in Venice

Don’t pursue economic growth at expense of environment – report

“Pursuing economic growth at the expense of the environment is no longer an option as Europe faces “unprecedented” challenges from climate chaos, pollution, biodiversity loss and the overconsumption of natural resources, according to a report from Europe’s environmental watchdog.”   read more

 


What cost economic growth? Examining the consequences of Malta’s decade of plenty

“…. there are 83,000 people at risk of poverty or social exclusion in Malta, 2,000 more compared with 10 years before. The increase goes against the EU as a whole …. can this growth continue or at least stabilise for the next 10 years? … The advice from economists is that …  Malta requires a return to sustainable growth which is focused more on achieving a balance and direct approach towards the quality of growth, rather than the quantity of growth ….”

 


FT Harford Growth Dematerialised 2020 01.jpg

 


Fully Grown

Is low economic growth a sign of success?  Yes, says Dietrich Vollrath, an economics professor, in a new book reviewed by The Economist

Fully Grown: Why a Stagnant Economy is a Sign of Success. By Dietrich Vollrath.

 

 

 


 

 

%d bloggers like this: